|
Australasian Agribusiness Review - Vol. 13 - 2005Paper 10 Estimating The Cost Of Food Safety Regulation To The New Zealand Seafood Industry[1]Kay Cao, Oswin Maurer, Frank Scrimgeour and Chris Dake
Kay Cao, Department of Economics, Waikato University Management School, New Zealand Oswin Maurer, School of Economics and Management, Free University of Bozen - Bolzano, Italy Frank Scrimgeour, Department of Economics, Waikato Univeristy Management School, New Zealand Chris Dake, Systmes Modelling, AgResearch Ltd, Ruakura Research Centre, New Zealand AbstractIn New Zealand, the Animal Products Act (1999) required all animal product processing businesses to have a Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Points (HACCP) based Risk Management Program (RMP) by the end of 2002. The purpose of the Act is to manage food safety risks and to facilitate overseas market access. However the new regulation will potentially bring costs to businesses. This paper attempts to measure the effects of RMP requirements on the variable cost of production of the New Zealand seafood industry. Using the framework developed by Antle (2000), a cost function is estimated using census of production data from 1929 to 1998. Results show that variable costs could increase from 2 percent to 22 percent or from 2 cents to 19 cents per kilogram. Keywords: HACCP/RMP, compliance costs, seafood
IntroductionThe Animal Products Act 1999, which came into force in November 2002, reformed the New Zealand law that regulates the production and processing of animal products. The purposes of this legislative change are to manage associated risks and to facilitate overseas market access. It is stated in Section 2 of the Act that the instituted measures will ensure that all traded animal products are fit for their intended purpose and that risks to human or animal health arising from the production and processing of animal material and products will be minimised. The new legislation will also facilitate the entry of animal material and products into overseas markets by providing the controls and mechanisms needed to safeguard official assurances for entry into those markets (NZFSA, 2002). A core requirement of the Animal Products Act (1999) is that primary animal processing businesses must have a registered Risk Management Programme (RMP) by the end of 2002. As a RMP is based on the principles of HACCP, this requirement means that businesses are responsible for the design and development, evaluation, and registration of the RMP. They also have to assure that the RMP is operating as planned and achieving specified outcomes. A summary of business responsibilities regarding the implementation of RMP is provided in Table 1. Table 1: Risk Management Programs
Source: adapted from RMP Manual (MAF, 2000) The Animal Products Act 1999 applies to all animal materials and products derived from animals that are traded and used in New Zealand or exported from New Zealand. Industries covered by the Act include the meat and seafood industry. The dairy industry is not included as it is covered under the Dairy Industry Act 1952. The New Zealand seafood industry is a billion-dollar industry. Seafood exports in 2001 were worth a total of $1.4 billion (SeaFIC, 2002), which makes the industry the fourth largest export earner of the country. Having a robust food safety assurance system such as a HACCP-based RMP means that the industry can be confident it will be able to retain its overseas markets and gain access to some new ones. However, RMP will also bring extra costs to the production process. This paper attempts to measure this increase in the production costs of the seafood industry due to the implementation of RMP. The study uses the econometric approach developed by Antle (2000) to measure the impacts of HACCP-based RMP on the variable costs of production. A recent study on the costs of food safety management in the New Zealand meat industry has shown that HACCP/RMP could affect the operating efficiency of plants by slowing down the production process and this effect could make a significant proportion in the total cost of HACCP/RMP implementation (Cao et al, 2002). The paper is constructed into three major parts. Part 1 reviews the recent literature on quantifying food safety compliance costs. Part 2 discusses the model used, data sources and the model estimation. Part 3 provides the estimates on cost of HACCP/RMP. Review of Methods Used to Quantify Food Safety CostsThe literature on quantifying food safety compliance costs can be categorised into three different approaches: (1) accounting approach, (2) economic-engineering approach, and (3) econometric approach. Accounting ApproachIn the accounting approach, costs are identified and calculated, without estimating a parametric representation of the cost function. Examples of recent studies using the accounting method include: the study of the Food Safety Inspection Service (FSIS) on the costs of HACCP to the US meat and poultry industry (Crutchfield et al, 1997) and the study of Colatore and Caswell on costs of HACCP to the US breaded fish industry (Colatore and Caswell, 2000). The FSIS study provides an ex ante estimate on the cost of HACCP regulation in the US meat and poultry industry which ranges from US$1 to US$1.2 billion over 20 years. Their estimate would be higher if the cost of production process modification was included (Robert et al, 1996). Ex post estimates of food safety costs are often higher than ex ante estimates. For example, Colatore and Caswell (2000) have shown that the cost of implementing only the minimum HACCP requirements comprises only 30 percent of the actual costs companies incurred. The incremental cost attributable to the regulation was estimated to be 20 percent of total costs. It has been argued that the accounting approach is unlikely to provide estimates of average costs for the whole industry due to the limited number of plants surveyed (Antle, 1999). Moreover, the accounting approach often underestimates costs, as the method is unable to measure effects of regulation on the overall operating efficiency of a plant. Economic-Engineering ApproachThe economic-engineering approach is described by Antle (1999) as a method using detailed engineering data combined with data on input costs to construct a quantitative model of the production process. This approach can provide a detailed picture of a plant’s production process, but it is costly to implement for each plant studied. Therefore, it may fail to capture the heterogeneity of the industry and may not provide cost information that is representative for the industry. The study of Jensen and Unnevehr (2000) on the cost of implementing HACCP to the US pork industry provides an example of this approach. It estimated the cost of individual technologies based on data from input supply firms and drew estimates of pathogen reduction from selected meat science studies. The cost of individual interventions varies from 3 cents per carcass for a cold water wash to 20 cents per carcass for hot water pasteurization. The study also found that to reduce pathogens to very low levels, the highest cost combination of rinses and sprays would cost 47 cents per carcass. Econometric ApproachWith the econometric approach, production cost functions are estimated and the estimation results are then used to measure potential costs of regulation. Although the method cannot provide cost details as in the other two methods, its advantages are that the cost function can capture the actual production behaviour of the firm and provide a statistical basis to test for related hypotheses. Moreover, regulatory impacts on productive efficiency can be measured. Antle (2000) has provided a detail framework of using this approach to measure the cost of HACCP to the US meat and poultry industry. HACCP cost estimate ranges from $535 million to $4.8 billion, or an average of 1 cent to 9 cents per pound for all meats. Model, data, and estimation of quality-adjusted cost functionCao et al (2002), following Antle (2000), discussed the theoretical framework to estimate changes in variable costs of production due to the implementation of a food safety management programme like HACCP. A similar approach will be used in this paper. Firstly, an empirical cost function, which incorporates quality and safety variables as well as other traditional variables such as input prices and output quantity, is specified and then estimated. Secondly, based on the estimates of the cost function, elasticity of cost with respect to safety is calculated, which is subsequently used to estimate changes in costs. ModelIf we characterised the quality-differentiated product by the triplet (y,s,q), where y is output quantity (i.e tonnes of seafood), s is product safety (i.e the level of microbial contamination), and q is a vector of other non-safety quality attributes (e.g nutrition, value, package, process), then the variable cost function which depends on both product quantity and quality can be specified as: VC = f(y,s,q,w,k). Here, w is a vector of input prices and k is the value of capital stock. Assuming input variables as consisting of labour (L) and other materials (M), the empirical cost function written in log-linear form, incorporating a time variable, can be specified as:
where
The cost share equation, derived using Shephard’s Lemma[2], is specified as follows:
where
Following Antle (2000), assuming firms are price-takers in a competitive market, a measure for product safety s can be derived and specified as: s = g(q,p,z,w,k). Here, p is the unit price of the product, z is a vector of other demand variables. Using the same approach as that of Cao et al (2002), we use New Zealand income per capita as a demand variable for the estimation. Empirically, the safety function can be written in log-liner form as: (3) Substitute (3) into (1) and (2) we have a cost function and a cost share function that consist of all observed variables, namely, wM, wL, y, k, qman, qmix, z, p. DataProduction data (wM, wL, y, k, qman, qmix,, p) were taken from New Zealand census of production for the seafood industry in the period from 1929 to 1998. Years with missing data are excluded, this leads to a total number of observations of 63. Deflators based on the Consumer Price Index were collected from the New Zealand Official Yearbook 2000. New Zealand per capita income for the period was taken from Maddison (1995) and the Penn World Table (Heston and Summers, 2002). A statistical summary of the variables is presented in Table 2. EstimationThe translog cost function (1) and cost share equation (2) are estimated with the conditions for linear homogeneity[3] of the cost function imposed. A test for food safety exogeneity was also conducted. Safety exogeneity holds if food safety regulation does not affect productive efficiency and hence production cost of the seafood industry. For the cost function (1), safety exogeneity holds if and only if all safety coefficients are equal to zero (gS = gSi (i = y, M, L, k, t) = 0). Our test results strongly reject this hypothesis (p = 0). Further estimation results are presented in Table 3. Table 2. Statistical summary of variables (a)
Note: (a) All price variables are expressed in 1999 NZ$ unless stated otherwise, (b) wM is measured by Producer Price Index, base year 1982 (PPI=1000) (c) average annual salary (d) income variable is measured in 1990 international dollars
Table 3. Estimation results (Standard errors in parentheses)
The interaction term of safety and labour price gsL is negative which means that a higher labour price lowers the marginal cost of safety. On the contrary, as gsM has an opposite sign from gsL, a higher material price leads to higher marginal cost of safety. These results are similar to those estimated by Cao et al (2002) for the meat industry. However, in the case of the seafood industry, the interaction term of safety and capital gsk is negative which means that increasing capital stock leads to decreasing marginal cost of safety. Also, gsy being negative means higher rates of production are associated with lower marginal cost of safety. The interaction term of time and material bMt is positive which shows that, for seafood, technical change is material using. On the contrary, bLt is negative which implies that technical change is labour saving. In order to estimate impacts of food safety regulation on variable cost, elasticity of cost with respect to safety is calculated. Mean elasticity is derived based on safety elasticity at each observation[4]. Results show that food safety cost elasticities lie in the range of 0.67 to 1.37, with a mean of 1.11. The fact that the mean safety cost elasticity is positive shows that costs of production rise as the safety level increases. Cost of food safety regulationTo estimate the cost of food safety regulation, changes in variable cost of production due to food safety regulation such as HACCP are then calculated as follows:
where
The change in unit cost can be calculated as: u = DVC/y (5) where
Food safety cost is estimated for three different scenarios where the base safety levels (s) are 50%, 70%, and 90% respectively. The observed values of the independent variables in equation (4) and (5) for each scenario are presented in Table 4 below. Table 4. Variables for estimating food safety regulation (HACCP) cost
Note: (a) mean value of VC in 1999 dollars as in Table 2 (b) based on assumption on regulation effectiveness (Antle, 2000) (c) mean value of y as in Table 2 Estimation results (Table 5) show that for a mean variable cost of about $120 million, the increase in variable cost due to regulation would be in the range of $3 million to $27 million (or 2.5% to 22.5% respectively), depending on the product safety level of the plant before regulation. The unit cost estimate is in the range of 2 cents to 19 cents per kilogram. Cost incurred decreases as plant base safety level increases. Plants with a good product safety record (s = 90%) bear the least change in unit cost (2 cents) (Scenario 3), while plants with a relatively worse safety record (s = 50%) bear the highest cost (19 cents) (Scenario 1). Table 5. Increases in variable cost and unit cost for a 20% improvement in product safety (in 1999 dollars)
ConclusionUsing seafood census of production data from 1929 to 1998, we have estimated a model of quality-adjusted translog cost function for the New Zealand seafood industry. Estimation results are then used to estimate the increase in variable cost of production due to the implementation of HACCP/RMP. The elasticity of cost with respect to safety is estimated to be 1.11 for the study period. Hence, for a level of annual variable cost of about $120 million, the increase in variable cost is estimated to be in the range of $3 million to $27 million (2.5% to 22.5%). Cost per unit is estimated to be in the range of 2 cents to 19 cents per kilogram. Cao et al (2002) estimated changes in variable cost of production for the New Zealand meat industry due to HACCP/RMP to be from 5 cents to 48 cents per kilogram. The findings in this study show that food safety cost for the seafood industry is somewhat lower than the cost estimate for the meat industry. Further detailed analysis on industry production characteristics is needed to analyse this difference in food safety costs. The increase in cost represents the impact of regulation on the operating efficiency of firms. It could be additional variable costs (i.e. labour and material costs) associated with the slowdown of the slaughtering line due to monitoring, sampling and testing. These costs constitute just a part of the total cost of regulation, which includes other items such as costs of HACCP/RMP plan design and new capital investment. The study estimates costs of food safety regulation based on time series data. Similar estimations can be done for cross-sectional data or panel data. The advantages of cross-sectional data or panel data are that the effect of data aggregation is reduced and the impact on different firm sizes is revealed. However, a comprehensive survey of the industry is required in order to collect this type of data. ReferencesAntle, J.M. (2000). No such thing as a free safe lunch: the cost of food safety regulation in the meat industry. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82(2), 310-322. Cao, K., Scrimgeour, F., Dake, C., and Maurer, O. (2002). The cost of food safety regulation: an analysis of the effects on variable cost of production of the New Zealand red meat industry. Paper presented at the NZARES Conference, Blenheim, New Zealand. Coelli, T.J., Prasada Rao, D.S., and Battese, G.E. (1998), An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Colatore, C., and Caswell J.A. (2000). The cost of HACCP implementation in the seafood industry: a case study of breaded fish. In L. J. Unnevehr (Ed.), The economics of HACCP: costs and benefits (pp.45-68). St. Paul, Minnesota, USA: Eagan Press. Crutchfield S., Buzby J., Roberts T., Ollinger O., and Lin J.C.-T. (1997). An Economic assessment of food safety regulations: the new approach to meat and poultry inspection. ERS/USDA report no.755. Jensen, H. H., and Unnevehr, L. J. (2000). HACCP in pork processing: costs and benefits. In L. J. Unnevehr (Ed.), The economics of HACCP: costs and benefits (pp.29-44). St. Paul, Minnesota, USA: Eagan Press. Heston, A. and Summers, R. (2002). Penn World Table, available at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ Maddison, A. (1995). Monitoring the World Economy 1820-1992. Development Centre Studies, OECD. Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry (MAF). (2000). RMP Manual. Available at MAF Web site: http://www.nzfsa.govt.nz NZFSA (2002). Summary of the Animal Products Act 1999, available at http://www.nzfsa.govt.nz/ Roberts, T., Buzby, J. C., and Ollinger, M. (1996). Using benefit and cost information to evaluate a food safety regulation: HACCP for meat and poultry. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78, 1297-1301. SeaFIC (2002). New Zealand Seafood Industry Council Ltd web site, available at http://www.seafood.co.nz/ [1] The authors wish to thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments on an earlier draft. [2] Shephard’s Lema states that the private derivates of the cost function, with respect to the input prices, give the corresponding conditional input demand functions, which are the economically optimal input levels to produce the given output quantity (¶c/¶wi=xi). Apply this to the elasticity of cost w.r.t input price of the translog cost function yields the cost share equation (2). For more information, see for example, Coelli et al (1998). [3] For the translog cost function to be homogeneous of degree one, the following restrictions need to be applied to the parameters: åbi=1; åbij=0; åbiy=0. [4] Safety elasticity at each observation point E=gs -gsl*lnwm +gsl*lnwl +gsy*lny +gsk*lnk +bst*t |
Contact the University : Disclaimer & Copyright : Privacy : Accessibility |
Date Created: 03 June 2005 |
The University of Melbourne ABN: 84 002 705 224 |