Skip past navigation to main part of page
 
Land and Environment : Agribusiness Assoc. of Australia
---

Agribusiness Review - Vol. 7 - 1999

Paper 3
ISSN 1442-6951


Consumer and Import Taxes in the World Wine Market: Australia in International Perspective

Nicholas Berger and Kym Anderson

Revised June 1999

School of Economics and Centre for International Economic Studies University of Adelaide
Adelaide SA 5005
Tel: (61 8) 8303 4927
Fax: (61 8) 8223 1460
nberger@economics.adelaide.edu.au

Abstract

Virtually all countries tax the consumption of wine (and other alcoholic beverages). However, the rates of taxation, and the tax instruments used, vary enormously between countries. This paper details for all the OECD members plus some other countries the consumer tax equivalents (CTEs) of wine taxes as of 1996. It shows wholesale sales taxes, excise taxes, import tariffs, and value-added or goods-and-services taxes, expressed both in dollars per litre and as a percentage of what the retail price would be without those taxes. These are shown in aggregate and also separately for non-premium and premium wines (since many wine taxes are volumetric and so their percentage CTE rates vary with the price of wine). The CTE tends to be lower the larger a country's per capita production of wine. Australia and New Zealand are shown to have relatively very high wine CTEs. In Australia's case this is especially so for premium wine, because Australia uses a percentage tax rather than the commonly used volumetric tax measure. Moreover, the extent to which Australia is an outlier has increased considerably during the past 15 years. This has implications for the current debate over reforms to Australia's tax system. The paper concludes by pointing also to the high wine import tariffs in some countries, arguing that there is scope for trade negotiators to expand wine market access in East Asia especially as the next WTO trade negotiations begin at the end of 1999.

Keywords: consumer wine taxation, GST, excise taxes JEL codes: H21, H22, H23, F13

Summary

The Australian Government is in the midst of trying to introduce a goods-and-services tax (GST). In doing so it is proposing to replace the current wholesale sales tax on wine of 41 per cent with a top-up wholesale Wine ‘Equalization' Tax (WET) which, together with the GST, would bring in roughly the same tax revenue from domestic wine consumers as currently.

The proposed change in the tax regime raises at least four questions. First, why should wine continue to be seen as a source of additional government revenue when the main thrust of the GST proposal is to move to a broad-based uniform rate of indirect taxation across all products? Second, if revenue raising is no longer the reason to tax wine consumption, what is the evidence that the current rate is optimal in terms of offsetting net negative externalities from consuming alcohol in this form -- given that there is growing evidence of the positive health benefits from moderate wine consumption? Third, in so far as a volumetric tax is a more precise way of taxing alcohol consumption than an ad valorem (percentage) tax, why is an ad valorem tax instrument still being contemplated when most other countries use a volumetric tax? And fourth, if Australia is going to continue to keep wine taxes high by international standards, which means the industry will have to market an ever-rising share of its expanding production abroad, what scope is there for our trading partners to buy more wine through lowering their tariffs on wine imports?

This paper addresses each of these question. It calculates the consumer tax equivalents (CTEs) of the various wine (and beer) taxation measures, including from wine import tariffs/export subsidies, for the main wine-consuming and producing countries of the world, countries which together account for 85 per cent of global wine consumption. The paper compares Australia's recent and proposed rates and means of wine taxation with those adopted by other OECD countries, and draws out implications for the on-going tax reform debate in Australia. It finds that Australia (and New Zealand) have wine CTEs three times as high as the OECD average, and six times as high as in Europe's main wine-producing countries. Because Australia is almost unique in using an ad valorem rather than volumetric wine tax measure, the contrast is even starker if attention is focused just on premium wine: the above differences are roughly twice as large. When expressed on a per litre of alcohol basis, among OECD countries it is only in Sweden and Mexico that the CTE for premium wine relative to beer is significantly above that for Australia and New Zealand.

The wine CTE for Australia has gradually risen over the past 15 years from being below the OECD average. The rise in the ad valorem tax rate is only part of the explanation; the other part is due to the trebling in the pre-tax wholesale price of wine (because of wine quality improvements, the shift in preferences toward premium wines, and rapid growth in export demand).

Together these changes caused wine tax revenue to rise sevenfold in nominal value terms since 1986, or threefold as a percentage of total government revenue (from 0.15 to 0.45 per cent). Had the wine tax been volumetric rather than ad valorem even as recently as 1991, and that rate been frozen since then, Australia's premium wine CTE in ad valorem terms would have halved in aggregate and fallen by four-fifths for premium wine by now. And being in proportion to the amount of alcohol, that form of wine taxation also would have provided a much more efficient form of taxing the negative externality perceived to be associated with excessive drinking.

The final section notes the extent of import taxation of wine in different countries and thus the scope for wine consumption and import growth via trade liberalization. It shows that scope to be especially significant in East Asia.

The Australian Government is in the midst of trying to introduce a goods-and-services tax (GST). In doing so it is proposing to replace the current wholesale sales tax on wine of 41 per cent with a top-up wholesale Wine ‘Equalization' Tax (WET) which, together with the GST, would bring in roughly the same tax revenue from domestic wine consumers as currently. 1   An alternative proposal, pushed by some spirits industry and anti-alcohol interest groups, is to make the WET a much higher (volume-based) tax equivalent to the beer ‘equalization' tax that will be in place when the GST is operating. 2 Australia's rate of wine consumer taxation is already high by OECD standards, and especially by the standards of significant wine producing/exporting countries. It is also unusual in being ad valorem (percentage) rather than specific (cents per litre). Given the current review of the overall Australian tax system, now is an appropriate time to ask whether the current rate and instrument of consumer wine taxation in Australia is optimal. This paper's examination of Australia's wine taxation as compared with that of other countries is a contribution to that debate.

The rates of wine taxation, and the tax instruments used, vary enormously between countries. In some countries trade policy instruments are used instead of or in addition to direct consumer taxes (in which case they also provide support for domestic producers). Both necessarily affect the volume of international wine trade, and so are of interest also to wine exporters and to trade negotiators – including in Australia, given the industry's recently successful export-oriented growth strategy. This is especially so as trade negotiators prepare for the World Trade Organization's next round of multilateral trade negotiations, due to begin by the end of 1999. These data are also of interest to wine producers and consumers in New Zealand and other highly taxed countries who are wishing to lobby for lower consumer tax rates. As well, analysts seeking to examine the economic impact of tax, subsidy and trade policy reforms at home or abroad need such information. This is especially so for analysts seeking to build economic models of wine markets, for which purpose it is helpful to distinguish premium from non-premium wine. That distinction in turn makes it crucial to also distinguish specific from ad valorem tax measures, because the ad valorem consumer tax equivalent of a specific tax (cents per litre of wine or alcohol) falls with the price of the product. The aggregate ad valorem CTE therefore also falls in countries with specific wine taxes when the proportion of premium wine in total wine consumption rises over time, as it has been doing in most countries during the past decade or two.

This paper summarizes available rates of wine (and beer) consumer taxation, including from wine import tariffs/export subsidies, for the main wine-consuming and producing countries of the world. They have been compiled with the intention of inserting them in a partial equilibrium model of the world wine market that is currently being constructed for projections and policy analysis, but they are provided at this interim stage because of their usefulness in their own right. The rates reported refer to 1996, but just-released evidence for 1998 ( OECD 1999 ) suggests there have been few changes in the past two years.

The first section summarizes the methodology used for compiling and reporting the tax rates and the sources of tax rate data. Section two discusses the calculations of the consumer tax equivalents for the OECD and other countries for which data are available, countries which together account for 85 per cent of global wine consumption. Section three compares Australia's current and proposed rates and means of wine taxation with those adopted by other OECD countries, and draws out implications for the on-going tax reform debate in Australia. The final section notes the extent of import taxation of wine in different countries and thus the scope for wine consumption and import growth via trade liberalization, for example under APEC's regional reform agenda and the up-coming WTO multilateral trade negotiations expected to get under way in 2000.

1. Methodology and data sources

Since specific (volumetric, cents per litre) as well as ad valorem (percentage) tax rates are used in many countries, the consumer tax equivalent (CTE) in percentage terms typically varies with the price of wine. This distinction is important because in recent years the world wine market has been characterised by a trend towards premium wine consumption, and in some countries the volume of non-premium wine consumption has fallen greatly. We therefore identify the tax type (specific or ad valorem) and express the CTE in terms of dollars per litre or bottle as well as an ad valorem equivalent for two different retail pre-tax price levels: one for non-premium wine, the other for mid-range premium wine.

The contributions to the aggregate CTE by the three key tax instruments (import tariffs, excise or wholesale sales taxes (WST), and value-added or goods-and-services taxes (VAT/GST)) are detailed in Berger and Anderson (1999, Appendix Tables A1-A7). The present paper highlights the relative importance of border taxation in the total consumer tax on wine across countries, bearing in mind that import tariffs also protect local wine producers. It also tests the hypotheses that the wine CTE (excluding the VAT/GST), and the wine-beer taxation differential, are negatively correlated with a country's production of wine per capita. The main reasoning behind these hypotheses is that the more important is the wine industry in the national economy, the more lobbying power it has to argue against taxing domestic wine consumers (who are their main customers in most cases) 3 , and in particular to counter the lobbying from the local beer and spirits industries for a higher wine tax.

In the extreme circumstance where export demand is highly price elastic, an increase in the tax on domestic consumption simply causes more wine to be exported and domestic consumers bear the full burden of the tax. The reality typically is, however, that the majority of production is low-quality wine that is non-tradable because of its low value-to-volume ratio. Producers of such wine therefore share the burden of any tax on its domestic consumption.

The consumer tax equivalent (CTE) is defined as the difference between the tax-inclusive retail price and the pre-tax wholesale price plus retail marketing margin, expressed as a percentage of the latter. To estimate the CTE, numerous assumptions have to be made:

(1) We assume that imported and domestically produced wines are perfect substitutes. That is, we assume the domestic prices of all wines, not just those imported, are raised by the amount of the import tariff. The tariff portion of the price is then also subject to any domestic consumer tax. Given the heterogeneous nature of wine, it is unlikely that the average price of all wine will increase by the full amount of the tariff and moreso the less substitutability there is between domestically produced and foreign wines (which in practice differs by country of origin). This assumption inflates the estimated CTE above its true value in countries that are significant producers of wines that differ from their imports. However, this is more or less offset by our inability to include estimates of the contribution to the true CTE of non-tariff barriers to wine imports (and export subsidies, but the latter probably only apply to extra-European Union trade and amount currently to less than 2 per cent even there). The extent to which the tariff component of the CTE is over-estimated would be greatest for EU member countries, since they import the vast majority of their wine duty-free from other members of their customs union.

(2) Neither the average pre-tax retail price of a bottle of premium wine or a litre of non-premium wine, nor the shares of each of these types in national consumption, are reliably known for more than a handful of countries. Hence an average CTE for each country can be calculated only by assuming something about these values. For simplicity we calculate the CTE at two pre-tax retail price levels: $2.70 per litre for non-premium wine, and $9 per 750ml bottle for premium wine. These approximate the average prices in Australian dollars for these two categories of wine sold in Australia in 1995-97, the weighted average of which is $5.50 per litre using domestic sales volumes in that period as weights (when 70 per cent of consumption volume was non-premium – see Osmond and Anderson (1998, Table 10)). For simplicity that same set of average prices and the 70/30 split are used for calculating the aggregate CTE for all countries, but the CTE is also shown separately for those two product types.

(3) The assumed retail margin is the same across countries and is set at the estimated Australian rates of 25 per cent of the tax-inclusive wholesale price for non-premium wine and 33 per cent for premium wine. These retail margins provide conservative estimates of the CTE because they implicitly assume that 100 per cent of sales occur off licensed premises. 4

The data requirements for CTE calculations include import tariffs, excise or wholesale sales taxes, and value-added or goods-and-services taxes. The primary source for this information was the Brewers Association of Canada (1998). The data obtained from the BAC Survey was cross-checked with excise tax, wholesale sales tax and VAT/GST rates from the OECD (1997), and supplemented with import tariff data from the APEC applied tariff rates web site. 5   Any inconsistencies between data sources are either noted in calculations or were resolved through consultation with national and/or other international sources. Taxation data on Asian-Pacific developing countries were obtained from a recent survey by the Australian Trade Commission, the Australian Wine and Brandy Corporation and the Australian Wine Export Council ( ATC , AWBC and AWEC 1997).

The import tariff levied on a bottle of wine differs between countries based on the nominal duty and the tax instrument used. Depending on the importing country, a bottle of wine could face a specific (volume-based) tariff, an ad valorem (value-based) tariff or a tariff based on the volume of alcohol in the product. Specific tariffs based on volume are the most popular in Europe and the United States, while ad valorem tariffs based on product value are the norm in the Asia-Pacific region with the exception of Japan and Malaysia (see Berger and Anderson 1999, Appendix Table A1). 6

World wine consumption and production per capita volumes are taken from the statistical compendium recently compiled by Berger, Anderson and Stringe r (1998), which is based on FAO and OIV data. 7   To convert exchange rates to Australian dollar terms as at 2 January 1996, we draw on the IMF (1996).

In most countries the VAT for all alcoholic beverages is the same as the general rate. In some countries (Italy, Luxembourg, Portugal) it is less for wine though, and in Switzerland the rate is more for beer. The exceptions are shown in Berger and Anderson (1999, Appendix Table A2). Where the wine VAT rate is less than the general VAT rate, the difference is treated here as a consumer subsidy that is netted out when calculating the overall consumer tax equivalent.

2. CTE calculations

Berger and Anderson (1999, Appendix Tables A3 to A6) detail the calculations of the consumer tax equivalent (CTE) by tax instrument for non-premium and premium wine, expressed both in dollars and in percentages. Summaries of those estimates are shown in Tables 1 to 4, each of which is discussed in turn.

In Table 1 we show the CTE for a litre of wine, excluding VAT or GST, valued at the average pre-tax Australian retail price of A$5.50 in 1995-97. The reason for excluding the VAT/GST in this table is that such a general tax applies to all or most goods and services and so causes little distortion to wine consumption levels, and is set with virtually no consideration for the wine industry or any negative externalities associated with alcohol consumption. The average CTE across all countries in this study (85 per cent of global consumption) amounts to about 16 per cent or A$0.89 per litre. Australia and New Zealand have CTEs three times those levels. While the United Kingdom and Ireland tax wine more (and consume much less of it per capita), and the Scandavians have rates double those of New Zealand, the wine taxes of other Western European (and especially its wine-producing) countries are nearly half the global averages and one-sixth those of Australia – despite our over-estimation of the tariff component of their wine CTE (because we have not adjusted for the fact that the EU's common 12 per cent external import tariff does not apply to the vast majority of EU member country imports, since their imports come mostly from other EU members duty-free). North America and South Africa too, and even Japan and Russia, tax wine consumers much less than Australia. 8   The only other countries with higher tax rates are some East Asian developing countries. 9

Table 1 : Average Consumer tax equivalent (CTE) on wine (excluding VAT/GST)* and wine production and consumption per capita, various countries and country groups, Jan.1996.

CTE on wine that would retail at $5.50/litre Production per capita without taxes Consumption per capita OIV's estimated consumption Population

dollars

per cent

litres

litres

Australia 1996

2.64

48

32.8

18.2

3297

18.1

2001**

2.12

39

41.7

19.8

na

New Zealand

2.93

53

15.9

9.9

356.000

3.6

European wine producers

0.42

8

92.9

53.7

175.5

France

0.54

10

102.3

59.7

34795.000

58.3

Italy

0.34

6

104.8

62.3

35623.000

57.2

Greece

0.34

6

39.2

30.5

3200.000

10.5

Portugal

0.34

6

97.2

59.2

5800.000

9.8

Spain

0.34

6

75.3

37.2

14750.000

39.7

Scandanavians

5.86

107

0.0

13.5

23.745

Denmark

2.36

43

0.0

27.2

1414.000

5.2

Finland

6.63

121

0.0

5.2

267.000

5.1

Iceland

15.02

273

0.0

5.1

0.27

Norway

11.73

213

0.0

8.8

4.375

Sweden

7.11

129

0.0

12.7

1115.000

8.8

Other Western Europe

1.43

26

6.3

19.5

185.72

Austria

0.34

6

26.0

32.6

2640

8.1

Belgium

1.20

22

1.2

21.1

2237

10.6

Germany

0.34

6

10.1

22.8

18660

81.9

Ireland

6.26

114

0.0

7.3

263

3.6

Luxembourg

0.34

6

1.2

50.4

0.414

Netherlands

1.43

26

0.0

13.2

2058

15.6

Switzerland

1.90

35

16.9

41.2

7.11

United Kingdom

4.12

75

0.0

12.4

7243

58.4

NAFTA

0.73

13

5.4

5.8

391.8

United States

0.54

10

7.0

7.6

20463

269.4

Canada

0.73

13

1.0

6.7

1983

29.7

Mexico

2.79

51

2.0

0.2

140

92.7

Asia and Pacific

3.99

73

0.3

0.4

1464.1

Japan

2.10

38

0.7

1.2

1443

125.4

China

3.84

70

0.3

0.3

3941

1210.7

Malaysia

11.29

205

0.0

0.1

20.9

Korea

11.85

216

0.1

na

45.0

Thailand

6.81

124

0.0

0.1

59.0

Singapore

11.51

209

0.1

0.8

3.0

Other

South Africa

0.31

6

22.4

20.0

4056

42.4

Russian Federation

1.67

30

3.9

4.3

12500

293.5

ABOVE COUNTRIES

0.89

16

22.8

22.3

Memo: OECD-24***

0.78

14

28.1

26.0

World consumption shares are used to calculate the bold weighted average shares for country groups. Calculations assume non premium wine accounts for 70 per cent of total domestic wine consumption. 
**Australia 2001 calculations assume a WST of 32 per cent, wine production of 8.00 million hl and a population of 19.2 million.
***Excludes the new members: Korea, the Czech Republic, Mexico, Hungary and Poland.

There is a significant negative correlation between wine production per capita and the wine CTE. This is illustrated in Figure 1 . Evidently the more important is wine production in a country, the less inclined are governments to tax their wine consumers. One possible reason is simply relative lobbying strengths: the more significant is national wine production, the stronger the wine industry's lobby against wine taxes (on the assumption that producers share the burden of the tax because some of their output is non-tradable internationally -- see footnote 3 ); whereas in countries with little or no wine production, the local brewing and spirits industries would lobby for high taxes on that competing provider of alcohol.

Figure 1 : Comparing per capita wine production and the average CTE on wine (excluding VAT/GST), Australia, 1986, 1991, 1996 and 2001, and various other countries, 1996 

What is also clear from Figure 1 is that Australia and New Zealand are well above the 1996 log-linear regression line summarizing that negative relationship. That was not the case for Australia prior to the most recent wine tax hike: in 1991 when the WST was only about 32 per cent and production per capita was less, Australia was much closer to the regression line. And in 1986 it was slightly below that line. If a 10 per cent GST is introduced in Australia by 2001 and the wine WST is commensurately reduced from 41 per cent back to around 32 per cent (as currently proposed by the Treasury), Australia will move closer to the regression line in Figure 1 as shown – but only slightly closer, and it will not be as close as in the early 1990s, because production per capita is expanding so rapidly.

Table 2 presents similar information as in Table 1 but reports CTEs separately for non-premium and premium wine. What this shows is how much less premium wine consumers are taxed relative to consumers of non-premium wine in most countries: the average for the countries shown is 10 per cent for premium, compared with nearly three times that for non-premium. This is because of the use of specific rather than ad valorem taxes in most countries. Australia is one of the few exceptional countries in using only an ad valorem rate. Australia's premium wine consumers face a CTE five times greater than the OECD average, while its non-premium consumers face a CTE just twice the OECD average.

Table 2 : Consumer tax equivalents (CTEs) on non premium and premium wine (excluding VAT/GST)* and shares of world wine consumption, various countries and country groups, Jan.1996.

dollars

dollars

Australia

1.30

48

5.77

48

1.7

New Zealand

2.53

94

3.88

32

0.3

European wine producers

0.38

14

0.50

4

50.4

France

0.50

19

0.62

5

19.4

Italy

0.31

12

0.42

4

17.5

Greece

0.31

12

0.42

4

1.4

Portugal

0.31

12

0.42

4

3.0

Spain

0.31

12

0.42

4

9.1

Scandanavians

5.73

212

6.18

52

1.2

Denmark

2.29

85

2.53

21

0.5

Finland

6.48

240

6.98

58

0.1

Iceland

14.74

546

15.68

131

0.0

Norway

11.48

425

12.31

103

0.2

Sweden

6.95

257

7.48

62

0.4

Other Western Europe

1.38

51

1.55

13

11.8

Austria

0.31

12

0.42

4

0.8

Belgium

1.15

43

1.31

11

0.8

Germany

0.31

12

0.42

4

6.2

Ireland

6.12

227

6.60

55

0.1

Luxembourg

0.31

12

0.42

4

0.0

Netherlands

1.38

51

1.55

13

0.7

Switzerland

1.87

69

1.99

17

0.6

United Kingdom

4.01

149

4.36

36

2.6

NAFTA

0.61

23

1.00

8

9.2

United States

0.53

20

0.56

5

7.8

Canada

0.72

27

0.77

6

0.7

Mexico

1.37

51

6.11

51

0.7

Asia and Pacific

2.33

86

7.87

66

2.4

Japan

1.48

55

3.56

30

0.7

China

1.89

70

8.40

70

1.5

Malaysia

10.67

395

12.73

106

0.0

Korea

5.83

216

25.91

216

0.1

Thailand

3.35

124

14.88

124

0.0

Singapore

11.29

418

12.01

100

0.1

Other

South Africa

0.30

11

0.32

3

3.2

Russian Federation

1.37

51

2.36

20

4.6

ABOVE COUNTRIES

0.75

28

1.20

10

84.8

Memo: OECD

0.69

26

0.98

8

75.3

*World consumption shares are used to calculate the bold weighted averages for country groups.
Slovenia 0.09 4 0.08 1
Estonia 1.31 49 1.05 9
Lithuania 1.58 59 1.26 11

Table 3 is similar to Table 2 except that the VAT/GST is included where applicable. While that lowers the extent to which Australia is an outlier in aggregate (column 5), its CTE remains above the OECD average even for non-premium wine and still more than twice as high for premium wine. (New Zealand's 12.5 per cent GST causes its CTE on non-premium wine to remain more than three times the VAT-inclusive CTE of the European wine-producing countries.)

Table 3 : Consumer tax equivalents on wine (incl. VAT/GST)* and VAT/GST rates, various countries and country groups, Jan.1996.

CTE on various wine types that would retail at the following prices without taxes:

Non premium $2.70/litre

Premium  $9/750ml bottle

Wtd. average $5.50/litre

VAT/GST  (wine- specific rate)

Share of world wine consumption volume

dollars

per cent

dollars

per cent

per cent

per cent

per cent

Australia

1.30

48

4.32

48

48

0

1.7

Australia 2001

1.42

52

4.72

52

52

10

1.7

New Zealand

3.18

118

4.40

49

72

12.5

0.3

European wine producers

0.92

34

1.99

22

26

50.4

France

1.16

43

2.42

27

32

20.6

19.4

Italy

0.79

29

1.81

20

23

16

17.5

Greece

0.85

32

1.99

22

25

18

1.4

Portugal

0.46

17

0.78

9

12

5

3

Spain

0.79

29

1.81

20

23

16

9.1

Scandanavians

7.76

287

7.95

88

157

1.2

Denmark

3.54

131

4.62

51

79

25

0.5

Finland

8.50

315

8.37

93

169

22

0.1

Iceland

19.01

704

16.85

187

365

24.5

0

Norway

14.74

546

13.42

149

285

23

0.2

Sweden

9.36

347

9.26

103

187

25

0.4

Other Western Europe

2.04

76

2.80

31

46

11.8

Austria

0.91

34

2.18

24

27

20

0.8

Belgium

1.96

73

3.08

34

47

21

0.8

Germany

0.76

28

1.71

19

22

15

6.2

Ireland

7.97

295

7.88

88

159

21

0.1

Luxembourg

0.67

25

1.43

16

19

12

0

Netherlands

2.09

77

2.94

33

48

17.5

0.7

Switzerland

2.16

80

2.17

24

43

6.5

0.6

United Kingdom

5.19

192

5.42

60

105

17.5

2.6

NAFTA

0.69

26

1.02

11

16

9.2

United States

0.53

20

0.42

5

10

0

7.8

Canada

1.24

46

2.03

23

30

7

0.7

Mexico

1.99

74

6.62

74

73

15

0.7

Asia and Pacific

3.19

118

8.73

97

104

2.4

Japan

1.60

59

3.02

34

42

3

0.7

China

3.13

116

10.43

116

116

17

1.5

Malaysia

10.67

395

12.28

136

205

0

0

Korea

6.68

247

22.27

247

247

10

0.1

Thailand

3.77

140

12.57

140

139

7

0

Singapore

11.71

434

9.55

106

218

3

0.1

Other

South Africa

0.72

27

1.54

17

20

14

3.2

Russian Federation

2.19

81

3.92

44

56

20

4.6

ABOVE COUNTRIES

1.09

40

2.05

23

29

100.0

Memo: OECD-24

1.20

44

2.16

24

31

75.3

*World consumption shares are used to calculate the bold weighted average shares for country groups.

(1) Includes a 10 per cent GST and ad valorem wine equalisation wholesale sales tax (WST). With a 10 per cent GST the WST on wine would fall from 41 per cent to 28 per cent to ensure a constant retail price.
(2) Includes a 10 per cent GST and specific tax set at the level required to maintain a constant retail price on a litre of wine that would retail at $2.7 without taxes.

How do countries' wine CTEs compare relative to beer CTEs? In Table 4 three different comparisons are shown between the beer CTEs (including VAT/GST) for a standard beer with 4.5 per cent alcohol and the wine CTEs of Table 3 : percentage CTE rates, CTEs per litre of beverage, and CTEs per litre of alcohol. From the first pair of columns in Table 4 the final row shows that premium wine is taxed in percentage terms only about one-third as much as beer in the OECD on average, while non-premium wine is taxed two-thirds as much as beer. Australia falls half way between those two, that is, it taxes non-premium wine relative to beer less and premium wine relative to beer more than other OECD countries (while New Zealand taxes both types of wine relative to beer at twice the OECD average).

When CTEs are expressed on a per litre of beverage basis, however, in the OECD on average non-premium wine is taxed slightly more heavily than beer and premium wine is taxed three times as much as beer (middle pair of columns in Table 4 ). Even for Australia the non-premium wine tax almost matches that of beer by this measure, and the premium wine CTE is more than four times that for beer. These higher ratios result from the fact that even non-premium wine is more expensive per litre than beer. Wine at around 12.5 per cent alcohol is more alcoholic than beer though, so when the comparison is made on a per-litre-of-alcohol basis, only the premium wine CTE exceeds that for beer (final columns of Table 4). For Australia that final comparison is especially stark: non-premium wine is taxed at only one-third the rate of beer per unit of alcohol, while premium wine is taxed at 50 per cent above that beer rate – more than twice the non-premium/premium gap of the OECD average. Notice that only in Sweden and Mexico is the CTE for premium wine relative to beer, on a per-litre-of-alcohol basis, significantly above that ratio for Australia and New Zealand.

Table 4 : Wine CTE as a percentage of beer CTE, various countries and country groups, Jan. 1996.

Percentage CTE rates CTE per litre of beverage CTE per litre of alcohol
Non premium wine ($2.70/litre) Premium ($9/750ml bottle Non premium Premium Non premium Premium

Australia

52

52

97

0

34

0

Australia 2001*

57

57

106

0

37

0

New Zealand

148

61

276

0

96

0

European wine producers

64

42

120

0

41

0

France

81

51

152

0

52

0

Italy

47

32

88

0

30

0

Greece

na

na

na

na

na

na

Portugal

29

15

55

0

19

0

Spain

61

42

114

0

39

0

Scandanavians

179

55

335

0

116

0

Denmark

120

47

225

0

78

0

Finland

124

37

232

0

80

0

Iceland

na

na

na

na

na

na

Norway

181

49

338

0

117

0

Sweden

356

106

665

0

230

0

Other Western Europe

98

40

180

0

62

0

Austria

123

88

98

0

34

0

Belgium

106

50

199

0

69

0

Germany

56

38

105

0

36

0

Ireland

158

47

296

0

102

0

Luxembourg

53

34

99

0

34

0

Netherlands

116

49

216

0

75

0

Switzerland

186

56

349

0

121

0

United Kingdom

145

45

271

0

94

0

NAFTA

122

54

228

0

79

0

United States

162

39

302

0

105

0

Canada

71

35

134

0

46

0

Mexico

233

233

437

0

151

0

Japan

27

15

50

0

17

0

Memo: OECD-24

69

37

128

0

44

0

* Includes a 10 per cent GST and ad valorem beer equalisation sales tax (ie the tax on beer is assumed to be unchanged if the GST is introduced by 2001). With a 10 per cent GST the ad valorem wholesale sales tax on wine is assumed to fall from 37 per cent to 24.5 per cent to ensure a constant retail price. The The weights used to get the regional aggregates are national shares of world wine consumption volume.

These comparisons suggest that if Australia were to copy the European wine-producing countries' relative tax structure, or even that of the OECD average, it would switch to a volumetric wine tax that would be only slightly higher than the current tax for non-premium wine, but would be at least one-third lower on average for premium wine (see final two columns of Table 4 ).

3. Implications relevant to Australia's tax reform debate

This survey raises at least two questions of relevance to the wine tax component of Australia's current tax reform debate: on the level of wine taxation, and on whether the tax measure should remain ad valorem.

In addressing the question of whether Australia is over-taxing its wine consumers, the first point to make is that the move to a GST diminishes greatly the justification for taxing alcohol for revenue-raising reasons. Just as the government argues that there should be no exemptions from the GST (on grounds of administrative tax simplicity and to avoid socially unproductive lobbying), so it could be argued that there is no need for add-on consumer taxes simply to raise revenue. At the very least it should be acknowledged that if the administrative cost of raising more government revenue via indirect taxes is less under a GST, the case for relying as much on wine taxation would have less force: since wine provides less that 0.5 per cent of all government tax revenue, a very slightly higher GST on all products would be enough to raise the revenue provided by current taxation of wine. Nor can State Governments complain that they would be denied their current revenue equivalent of a 15 per cent tax on alcohol sales, since the Federal Government proposal is to give them all the GST revenue: again, a very slight adjustment to the revenue-sharing formula to be included in the tax reform package is all that would be needed to accommodate that concern.

The other justification typically given for taxing alcoholic beverages is to compensate society for the negative externalities associated with alcohol consumption. That justification has become clouded in recent years as more evidence of the health benefits of moderate wine comsumption with meals accumulates ( WFA 1998a, Appendixes A, B, and C). But even if those negative externalities are greater than any positive health externalities, are they so much larger in Australia than elsewhere as the above CTEs imply -- or are wine consumers in the vast majority of OECD countries being under-taxed? It is clear from the data above that Australia taxes wine exceptionally heavily by OECD standards and especially compared with those countries that are sizeable wine producers and consumers per capita. This is particularly so for premium wine, where only the Nordic countries have significantly higher wine CTEs than Australia (ignoring VAT/GST – see column 4 of Table 2 ). Only Sweden and Mexico tax premium wine relative to beer consumption substantially more than does Australia. And those comparisons with European countries would be even more stark if less than the full pass-though of import tariffs had been assumed in calculating the CTEs.

In addition to looking across countries, it is also helpful to examine Australia's wine tax over time. While beer and spirits have always attracted excise taxes in Australia, it was not until August 1970 that an excise tax (of 50 cents per gallon) was imposed on wine. So unpopular was the tax that it was halved in March 1992 and completely removed in December 1972 by the new Whitlam Labor Government. The Fraser Coalition Government that followed resisted re-introducing it, but the new Hawke Labor Government chose to impose a 10 per cent wholesale sales tax in its August 1984 budget. The WST was subsequently raised to 20 per cent in the August 1986 budget. It stayed at that level until the Labor Government raised it to 31 per cent in the August 1993 budget. The outcry that followed led to its reduction to 22 per cent in October of that year and the setting up of an inquiry into the industry and its taxation ( Industry Commission 1995). In the event, the WST was raised by two percentage points in July 1994 and again in July 1995. Since then it has remained at 26 per cent. Meanwhile, State government franchise fees on wine sales had risen to close to 15 per cent at the wholesale level. Since August 1997 those fees have been collected by the Federal Government on behalf of the States, following a High Court ruling declaring State franchise fees unconstitutional. Thus the WST since then has been a total of 41 per cent.

The relatively high rate of tax on (especially premium) wine consumption in Australia has been worsening over the past decade or so not just because Australia's rate of wine tax has risen several times since the mid-1980s, but also because it has always been an ad valorem tax. The type of measure is important because, unlike with a specific tax, the degree of taxation via an ad valorem tax has not become less significant with the rise in both the price of (especially premium) wine and the share of premium in total wine consumption. As Table 5 shows, the premium share of Australia's total wine consumption has risen from 20 per cent to a projected 36 per cent over the 15 years from the mid-1980s, the average pre-tax wholesale price has already risen more than three-fold for that reason and because of quality improvements, export demand growth and general inflation, and the wholesale sales tax rate (including State liquor licence fees) has more than doubled. 10   For all these reasons, the nominal value of wine tax revenue is estimated to have risen sevenfold since the mid-1980s. Figure 2 illustrates that growth, and shows it also as a percentage of total government revenue -- which has trebled over that period, from 0.15 to 0.45 per cent.

Figure 2 : Value of wine tax revenue and wine's share of total government revenue, 1983/84 to 1997/98

Table 5 : Composition, price and tax on wine consumption, Australia, 1985-86 to 2000-01

Premium share (%) of domestic wine consumption volume

Pre-tax wholesale price of wine sold in Australia (A$/litre)

Wholesale sales tax including State licence fees a (%)

Wholesale sales tax including State licence fees a ($m)

1985-86

20.1

1.65

19

102

1990-91

24.3

2.24

32

213

1995-96

28.5

4.30

41

545

1997-98

31.2

5.16

41

717

2000-01

36.0

n.a.

43 b

n.a.

a The State licence fees are assumed to have risen on average from 9 to 12 and then to 15 per cent at the wholesale level from 1986 to 1991 and 1996, before being collected on behalf of the states at a rate of 15 per cent after August 1997, following the High Court ruling the fees unconstitutional.
b Includes the WST-equivalent of the proposed GST, assuming the 10 per cent GST is introduced in July 2000 and that the top-up wine tax has the government's proposed extra 1.9 percentage points added to the current rate.
Source: Updated from Osmond and Anderson (1998, Tables 9, 10) and WFA (1998b, p. 21).

Had the consumer tax been specific rather than ad valorem even as recently as 1991 (when at 32 per cent it would have been equivalent to 72 cents per litre of wine or about $5.70 per litre of alcohol), and had the specific rate not changed from that level since then, Australia's wine CTE in ad valorem terms would have halved in aggregate and fallen by more than four-fifths for premium wine by now. In terms of Figure 1, that would have put Australia almost exactly on the regression line in 1998 – still well above the average for all the large wine-producing countries, but much closer than currently. And being in proportion to the amount of alcohol, that form of wine taxation also would have provided a more efficient form of taxing the negative externality perceived to be associated with excessive drinking. 11

This difference in outcomes raises the question as to why Australia continues with an ad valorem measure. The main Australian wine industry bodies still lobby for the retention of ad valorem taxation rather than a switch to a specific (volumetric) tax. This is partly out of fear that such a switch might be accompanied by a rise in the tax rate to match that of beer, and partly because they do not acknowledge that wine deserves a ‘sin' tax. The above evidence suggests that while the wine rate is no more than half that of beer in ad valorem CTE terms or per litre of alcohol, it is already more than the beer rate when expressed per litre of beverage.

Even so, industry bodies expect the Government would argue that, notwithstanding the possible positive health benefits of moderate wine consumption with meals, at least non-premium wine has net negative externalities associated with its consumption that warrant a CTE higher than at present. 12   Even if a change in tax instrument lowered the CTE on premium wine, large producers (as well as consumers) of non-premium wine could be made worse off, given the non-tradability of that wine (see footnote 3 above). Their share of all wine firms and grapegrowers is continuing to fall over time, however, and already about 5 per cent of non-premium wine is imported to make up for shortfalls as Australian grapegrowers convert more land to premium varieties. As well, the non-premium share of Australia's total wine sales volume has fallen from more than 70 per cent to less than 50 per cent in the latter half of the 1990s. Should these trends continue, there may come a time early next century when the balance of interest group preferences will swing towards a volumetric tax in place of an ad valorem WST or (if the GST is introduced) WET. That is less likely the more the price of wine falls as global supplies expand, however – and the more people continue to believe the government would not peg a volumetric tax but rather raise it over time to bring in more revenue.

4. Wine import taxes and the scope for trade reform

Finally, what do the data have to say about trade distortions? If Australia's high consumer tax on wine does not come down if/when the GST is introduced, the wine industry will have to continue to expand its export sales to dispose of the rapidly expanding crush. Indeed export sales could well exceed domestic sales early next century. One way the surplus from Australia and other expanding regions could be accommodated is for markets protected by trade barriers to open up more, and for wine export subsidies to be eliminated.

Export subsidies appear to be unimportant even in the European Union, where there has been a gradual running down of the wine surplus generated by high support prices in the past. At present they probably amount to less than 2 per cent for the EU exporting countries. 13   Import barriers are non-trivial though. Numerous non-tariff barriers exist and provide scope for trade liberalization (e.g., through harmonization or mutual recognition of technical standards), but because of a lack of quantifiable information only tariffs are reported in Table 6 . Tariffs are zero or unimportant within the so-called free-trade areas of the EU, NAFTA and the ANZCER. But non-EU countries face a A$0.32 tariff barrier into the massive EU wine market for an average bottle of premium wine, a A$1.50 barrier into the Swiss market, and barriers several times that into some of East Asia's markets -- where premium wine imports have begun to grow rapidly, albeit from a low base. These data suggest there are considerable opportunities for further export growth for producers in the Southern Hemisphere and California, for example by pushing for wine import liberalization as part of the next WTO multilateral trade negotiations which are due to begin at the end of 1999. Given the very small proportion of alcohol consumed as wine in East Asia (see Table 7 ), due at least in part to the high tariffs on wine imports, trade negotiators' attention might be focused on that region especially as income growth rates there recover after the present downturn. Removing Australia's own 5 per cent tariff on wine imports would be a small price for the domestic industry to pay as a quid pro quo for lower import barriers abroad for Australian wine – and a small reprieve for Australia's highly taxed wine consumers as they await the outcome of the tax reform debate.

Table 6 : Import tariffs on non premium and premium wine and the weighted tariff on wine as a per cent of the average wine CTE (excl. VAT/GST). various countries and country groups, Jan.1996.

Non premium $2.70/litre

Premium $9/750ml bottle

Wtd. tariff as a % of ave. wine CTE ($5.50/litre)

dollars

per cent

dollars

per cent

per cent

Australia

0.14

5

0.45

5

10

Australia 2001

0.14

5

0.45

5

13

New Zealand

0.35

13

1.17

13

17

European wine producers

France

0.31

12

0.32

4

63

Italy

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Greece

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Portugal

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Spain

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Scandanavians

Denmark

0.31

12

0.32

4

14

Finland

0.31

12

0.32

4

5

Iceland

0.00

0

0.00

0

0

Norway

0.31

12

0.32

4

3

Sweden

0.31

12

0.32

4

5

Other Western Europe

Austria

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Belgium

0.31

12

0.32

4

28

Germany

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Ireland

0.31

12

0.32

4

5

Luxembourg

0.31

12

0.32

4

100

Netherlands

0.31

12

0.32

4

23

Switzerland

1.87

69

1.49

17

100

United Kingdom

0.31

12

0.32

4

8

NAFTA

United States

0.16

6

0.13

1

30

Canada

0.09

3

0.07

1

12

Mexico

0.54

20

1.80

20

40

Asia and Pacific

Japan

0.58

21

1.95

22

45

China

1.89

70

6.30

70

100

Malaysia

8.93

331

9.50

106

83

Korea

0.81

30

2.70

30

14

Thailand

1.62

60

5.40

60

48

Singapore

11.29

418

9.01

100

100

Other

South Africa

0.14

5

0.11

1

47

Russian Federation

0.27

10

0.88

10

24

Table 7 : Alcohol consumption per capita by type of beverage, Western Pacific countries, 1986 and 1996

(litres of alcohol per year)

Wine

Beer

Spirits

TOTAL

Australia

1986

1996

2.8

2.4

5.2

4.3

1.3

1.4

9.0

7.5

New Zealand

1986

1996

2.2

2.2

5.4

4.4

1.4

1.2

8.1

6.8

Japan

1986

1996

0.09

0.13

1.8

2.4

2.4

2.2

5.9

6.6

Taiwan

1986

1996

0.04

0.07

0.9

1.1

0.1

0.3

2.3

2.7

China

1986

1996

0.01

0.02

0.02

0.06

1.5

3.0

1.5

3.7

Singapore

1986

1996

0.07

0.10

n.a.

0.93

0.4

0.5

0.5

1.6

Malaysia

1986

1996

0.01

0.01

0.27

0.43

0.1

0.1

0.4

0.6

Thailand

1986

1996

0.00

0.01

0.09

0.50

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.7

 Source: PVGD (1997).

Footnotes

1- Government revenue raising is a significant, but not the only, reason for the current tax. Its relevance should diminish in the context of a major tax reform aimed at introducing a general goods-and-services tax. An additional motivation for taxing wine and other alcoholic beverages is to offset perceived negative health and other social externalities from excessive drinking. In the case of wine, however, there are reputed to be positive health benefits from moderate drinking, especially of red dry wine. An overview assessment of those externalities is provided in Freebairn (1995). More-detailed assessments from the industry's viewpoint, together with very extensive bibliographies, are included in WFA (1998a, Appendixes A, B and C).

2 - For an empirical analysis of these and other wine tax options for Australia using an economy-wide model, see Wittwer and Anderson (1998).

3 - In the extreme circumstance where export demand is highly price elastic, an increase in the tax on domestic consumption simply causes more wine to be exported and domestic consumers bear the full burden of the tax. The reality typically is, however, that the majority of production is low-quality wine that is non-tradable because of its low value-to-volume ratio. Producers of such wine therefore share the burden of any tax on its domestic consumption.

4 - In Australia currently only about 80 per cent of all wine consumption and 70 per cent of premium wine consumption occurs off licenced premises. The average margin for sales in licenced restaurants in Australia is estimated to be around 120 per cent for premium wine and more than 250 per cent for non-premium wine ( Strachan 1999).

5 - See http://www.apectariff.org

6 - In Japan the import tariff is calculated as the lesser of 196 yen per litre or 35 per cent of product value, which means that as the per unit value of wine imports into Japan increases, the specific duty tends to become operative. In Malaysia the duty on wine is based on alcoholic volume in the same way that the excise tax on spirits is treated in virtually all countries.

7 - The United Nations' Rome-based Food and Agriculture Organisation, and the Paris-based Office International de la Vigne et du Vin. In the case of Australia in Figure 1, three-year averages of production are used around the 1991 and 1996 vintages to reduce the effect of seasonal fluctuations, while the projections for 2001 are from Strachan (1998).

8 - The calculated CTEs for North America are ‘lower bound' estimates of the true CTEs as the price effects of state monopoly controls on the distribution of alcohol in Canada and myriad state-controlled non-tariff barriers to wine trade into the United States have not been quantified. It has been alleged, for example, that the Liquor Control Board of Ontario (possibly the world's biggest importer of wine) applies a two-thirds mark-up on imported wine.

9 - Comprehensive data from Eastern Europe are not available. However, unpublished numbers provided by Scott (1999) suggest that domestic wine taxes (not including any import taxes) in Estonia and Lithuania are only about 50 per cent above the OECD average shown in Table 1 while those in Slovenia are well below that average.

10 - For an analysis of the relative importance of these and other factors on the recent and prospective growth of Australia's wine production and exports, see Wittwer and Anderson (1999).

11 - A volumetric tax in place of an ad valorem tax also would have encouraged a greater swing towards premium wine consumption, as the analysis by Barzel (1976) makes clear.

12 - A counter-argument put by Ekelund and Gan t (1997) is that, in so far as consumers would substitute to non-wine stimulants if non-premium wine was taxed more, they may cause even more social harm than at present.

13 - In 1995 the EU-15 spent 37 million ECU on wine export subsidies, and it is capped under Uruguay Round commitments to 39 million by 2000 ( Tracy 1997). This equates to about 1.6 per cent of the value of extra-EU wine trade. See also Polidori , Rocchi and Stefani (1998). With new plantings of premium winegrapes rapidly expanding in Europe, however, surplus wine ‘lakes' could well re-appear in the future unless farm export subsidies are outlawed following the next round of WTO negotiations.

References

ATC , AWBC and AWEC (1998), 1997 Export Market Grid , Adelaide: Australian Wine and Brandy Corporation.

Barzel , Y. (1976), 'An Alternative Approach to the Analysis of Taxation', Journal of Political Economy 84(6): 1177-98, December.

Berger , N. and K. Anderson (1999), ‘Consumer and Import Taxes in the World Wine Market: Australia in International Perspective', CIES Policy Discussion Paper No. 99/03, February.

Berger, N., K. Anderson and R. Stringer (1998), Trends in the World Wine Market, 1961 to 1996: A Statistical Compendium , Adelaide: Centre for International Economic Studies, June.

Brewers Association of Canada (1998), International Survey, Alcoholic Beverage Taxation and Control Policies: Ninth Edition , Ottawa: Brewers Association of Canada.

Ekelund , R.B. and P. Gant (1997), 'Excise tqaxes, Social Costs, and the Consumption of Wine', pp. 247-70 in Taxing Choice: The Predatory Politics of Fiscal Discrimination , edited by W.F. Shugart, New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers.

Freebairn , J. (1995), ‘Consumption Taxation of Wine', Invited Paper presented to the annual Conference of Economists, University of Adelaide, September.

IMF (1996), International Financial Statistics , Washington: International Monetary Fund, March.

Industry Commission (1995), Winegrape and Wine Industry in Australia , Canberra: Industry Commission.

OECD (1997), Consumption Tax Trends: Second Edition , Paris: OECD, January (a bi-annual publication).

OECD (1999), Consumption Tax Trends: Third Edition , Paris: OECD, January (a bi-annual publication).

Osmond , R. and K. Anderson (1998), Trends and Cycles in the Australian Wine Industry, 1850 to 2000 , Adelaide: Centre for International Economic Studies, June.

Polidori , R., B. Rocchi and G. Stefani (1998), ‘Reform of the CAP and the EU Wine Sector', pp. 29-40 in CAP Reform: The Southern Products , edited by M. Tracy, Genappe, Belgium: Agricultural Policy Studies.

PVGD (1997), World Drink Trends 1997 , Henley-on-Thames: NTC Publications for Productschap Voor Gesdistilleerede Dranken (the Commodity Board for the Distilled Spirits Industry), Schiedam, Netherlands.

Scott , A. (1999), Personal communication, OECD Secretariat, Paris, 14 January.

Strachan , S. (1998), ‘Projections of Australian Exports and Domestic Sales to 2003', WFA paper presented to the 1998 Wine Industry Outlook Conference, Melbourne, 21 October.

Strachan, S. (1999), Personal communication, Winemakers' Federation of Australia, Adelaide, 6 January.

Tracy , M. (1997), Agricultural Policy in the European Union and Other Market Economies (Second Edition), Genappe, Belgium: Agricultural Policy Studies.

WFA (1998a), Submission to the Tax Consultative Task Force on Taxation Reform , Adelaide: Winemakers' Federation of Australia, March.

WFA (1998b), 1998 Statistical Report , Adelaide: Winemakers' Federation of Australia.

Wittwer , G. and K. Anderson (1998), Tax Reform and the Australian Wine Industry , Adelaide: Centre for International Economic Studies, June. A much-revised version has since appeared as 'Impact of Tax Reform on the Australian Wine Industry: A CGE Analysis', CIES Discussion Paper 99/08, University of Adelaide, May 1999.

Wittwer, G. and K. Anderson (1999), ‘Accounting for Growth in Australia's Wine Industry, 1986 to 2003', Paper presented to the Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, Christchurch, 20-22 January.

top of pagetop of page

Contact us

Contact the University : Disclaimer & Copyright : Privacy : Accessibility