Environmental
Policy Implementation Challenged by some Land Management Realities
John
Cary
Bureau
of Rural Sciences, Australia
T.S. Eliot observed that humankind cannot bear
too much reality. Ignorance of the realities that motivate changes in land
management practices in Australia will endanger the development of
appropriate policy approaches. A recent large-scale study of human and social
aspects of capacity to change to sustainable management practices, undertaken
for the National Land and Water Resources Audit (NLWRA), identified some
important realities that confront aspirations for significant and speedy
landscape change.
Let us consider some of these realities as
well as the place of community consensus and participation within the wider
instruments of policy for managing land degradation. Concern about land
degradation problems amongst Australian landholders is now well established.
While many landholders may not recognize subtle or insidious manifestations
of land degradation, most landholders recognize significant degradation
problems. In most areas of Australia some form of ‘landcare’ related work
is undertaken on more than a third of farms (Cary,
Barr, Aslin, Webb and Kelson 2001).
The
nature of management ‘technologies’
Polices to improve the management of degrading
land include land use change and the encouragement of change to more
sustainable management practices within given land uses. Encouragement of
landholders to adopt more sustainable management practices is easy where,
financially, they believe they will be better off or no worse off by the
change. If, however, landowners believe that they will be worse off
financially there is a serious impediment to adoption.
Sustainable practices, which provide economic
and other advantages, will generally be adopted more rapidly. In most cases,
any economic advantage will be influenced by commodity prices, which are
outside the control of farmers and can fluctuate significantly. Ideally,
sustainable practices should provide observable and positive consequences for
land managers over a short time frame rather than depending on
pro-environmental values of land managers.
Landholders generally seek to reduce the risk
of adopting a new practice. In a forthcoming publication Mara,
Pannell and Abadi Ghadim (2002) review the influence of
uncertainty and risk on adoption decisions. They emphasize the importance of
personal experience, experimentation and learning in the adoption process,
reflecting associated uncertainty and the adaptive nature of an adoption
decision for the decision-maker. Sustainable practices which are observable,
able to be experimented with and less complex will be more quickly adopted
than practices which are complex or where the outcomes are not able to be
observed or have long time lags before being observed.
Very often the economic advantage of a
particular sustainable management practice varies with location. It is to be
expected therefore that rate of adoption will vary between districts and
regions. This common-sense observation was first demonstrated for the
adoption of hybrid corn in regions of the United States by Zvi Griliches in
the ‘sixties’.
Cary,
Webb and Barr (2001) confirmed this locality effect for nine
resource management practices in Australia. It makes no sense to assume that
a practice with advantages in one location will yield the same advantages
elsewhere. Given Australia’s diverse environment few sustainable practices
have universal applicability. Sustainable practices with wider geographic
applicability, such as deep-rooted perennials (which usually need to be
accompanied by other complementary inputs), often provide only moderate
advantage to the landholder. Increased effort needs to be applied to identify
and develop locally applicable sustainable practices. Effort also needs to be
made to resist the temptation to promote these practices beyond localities
where their advantage has been established.
Resource and
social capacity
Farmers vary in their capacity
to change management practices. The linkages between socio-economic
characteristics of land managers and the use of sustainable practices were
explored by Cary et.
al. (2001). This analysis was based, in part, on data
collected in the Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics (ABARE)
annual resource management survey undertaken in conjunction with the
Australian Agricultural and Grazing Industries Survey and the Australian
Dairy Industry Survey. This research showed that it is difficult to predict
which landholders are more likely or less likely to change land management
practices.
The NLWRA study found the following factors
were useful as indicators of landowner capacity to change to sustainable
management practices:
·
participation in
occupation-related training
·
level of farm income
·
optimism about future farm
income
·
having a documented farm
plan
·
membership of Landcare
·
age.
In fact, most of these variables are not
particularly strong or reliable predictors (Table 1). For example membership
of community landcare was one of the 16 independent variables that were
explored. For 15 practices investigated, membership of community landcare was
found to be significantly associated with the adoption of only three
management practices.
Age is an important social characteristic
because it is an indicator of the structure of the agricultural workforce
that is changing in Australia, and changing differentially in different
localities. Farmer age seemed to have little influence on individual adoption
of management practices in the models tested (Table 1). It is unlikely that
any age relationship with adoption is linear. In other studies the influence
of age is often contradictory. However those who retire from farming are
usually older farmers and those approaching retirement age are less likely to
be making large environmental investments, particularly if they have also
been receiving lower incomes.
Table
1 Characteristics significantly
associated with practice adoption
Characteristic
|
Frequency
of significant associations
|
|
Predicted
direction
|
Non
predicted direction
|
State
of residence
|
9
|
|
Positive
financial expectations
|
7
|
1
|
Has
a farm plan
|
6
|
0
|
Recently
participated in training
|
6
|
0
|
Farm
planning incorporates concern about land degradation
|
6
|
0
|
Land
use intensity
|
4
|
2
|
Concerned
about inadequate technical resources to overcome land degradation
|
4
|
1
|
Closing
equity ratio
|
1
|
3
|
Landcare
membership (1998-99)
|
3
|
0
|
Length
of landcare membership
|
1
|
1
|
Concern
about inadequate financial resources to overcome land degradation
|
1
|
1
|
Property
management planning participation in last 3 years
|
2
|
0
|
Age
|
2
|
0
|
Farm
cash income
|
1
|
0
|
Farm
size
|
0
|
1
|
Profit at full equity
|
1
|
0
|
Table
1 summarises the frequency with which the characteristic variables
demonstrated statistically significant associations with practice adoption in
15 logit regression models for the use of 15 sustainable practices recorded
in the ABARE resource management survey.
Landholders’ expectations of their future
financial situation was one of the better predictors of the adoption of
sustainable management practices. In fact, financial outlook was more often
associated with practice adoption than were objectively measured indicators
of financial position. Similar associations between financial perceptions and
business behaviour can be observed in the wider economy. This highlights the
importance of perception in adoption behaviour. Farmers who feel secure in
their financial future are more likely to invest resources in adopting new
resource management practices. Feeling financially secure is an outcome not
just of current financial circumstances, but of future expectations and
psychological disposition.
These findings suggest strong limitations in
the utility of community landcare alone to drive the adoption of sustainable
land management practices. Generally, financial incentive and financial
capacity, skill capacity and appropriate useful technology are necessary
concomitants for changes in resource management behaviour. Stewardship values
and care about environmental ideals, on their own, are unlikely to bring
about effective change in resource management behaviour.
The influence of
changing environmental values
Pro-environmental values have been important
in fostering awareness of land degradation, but they have a relatively minor
influence on the adoption of sustainable practices. For
the most part, stewardship and landcare values have more significant indirect
than direct effects on resource management behaviour. They provide a
consensus for community action (and for the imposition of informal or formal
social constraints) but they have a much weaker direct influence on
individual action.
The effect of positive environment values is
constrained by the influence of prevailing incentives or disincentives to
adopt a sustainable practice. Positive environment values interact with
external incentives or disincentives (such as costs, benefits, convenience,
or uncertainty of outcome of a given practice) to determine adoption
behaviour regarding sustainable practices. The effect of strongly positive
environmental attitudes on sustainable practice adoption tends to be
influential when there are no strong external incentives or disincentives for
undertaking the practice. (An urban example is kerbside recycling of domestic
waste.) Positive environmental attitudes have much less effect on behaviour
when external incentives or external disincentives are strong (for example
forgoing the convenience of the private automobile in favour of public
transport). In the latter case it is the external factors which usually
compel or prohibit the behaviour in question.
The strength of the external conditions
determines the bounds of influence of positive environmental attitudes and
values (Cary, Webb and Barr, 2001).
In situations where the private benefits are negative, or in open access
common property situations, the expectation that farmers will make
significant investments in public good activity for little or negative
financial return is usually doubtful. To paraphrase latter day philanthropist
George Soros, where there is a conflict between the common good and
self-interest, self-interest is likely to prevail. Policies to change
motivation via changing the stewardship ethic in the absence of other
enabling conditions are likely to achieve relatively little.
The
economic rationale for cooperative action
In confronting the realities facing policies
that rely on increasing environmental awareness to counter land degradation,
the implication is that there are strong limitations to what Landcare and
community action can achieve. However, inadequate information on which to
base localized action and high transaction costs for action suggest there is
frequent failure of markets. This works against individuals acting
independently and encourages some form of cooperative action to ameliorate
land degradation problems.
Local information and knowledge needed for
tackling land and water degradation is often deficient. It is often abstract
and catchment-based rather than based on concrete local empirical information
at the farm level. End of catchment discharge indicators of soil and river
salinisation may be known, but local impacts within catchment recharge and
discharge areas are generally inadequately identified. In situations where
externalities exist and individuals are unlikely to capture sufficient
benefits to act optimally, the externalities are likely to be complex with
the knowledge of external benefits and private costs rudimentary.
Even for the apparently straightforward task
of evaluating the use of perennial plants to control groundwater levels in
regions at risk of dryland salinisation Pannell (2001) identified a wide
range of ‘information’ difficulties facing landholders. He identified
that observability of treatment impacts on groundwater levels is low and
observations are costly; there are long time lags between treatment and
effect; and, in a common property groundwater problem, the effectiveness of a
local trial by an individual farmer may be compromised by non-trialing
neighbors.
While economists commonly favour the use of
market-based instruments to coordinate individual behaviour, in resource
management situations many transactions involve more complex relationships,
reflecting the inadequacy of information and the risks associated with the
transaction. Typically, these consequences give rise to transaction costs and
unequal distribution of knowledge between agents.
Transaction costs include the costs of search
and information, of safeguarding an agreement; of monitoring and enforcement,
and of adaptation for particular circumstances. When transaction costs are
high, businesses seek to internalize and reduce them, such as, by use of
formal contracts or business integration. Sometimes when transaction costs
are high economic transactions are facilitated by less formal, or other
socially institutionalized, arrangements.
Land degradation problems are frequently
characterised by low ‘agreed knowledge’. For example, ground water that
is transmissive between properties or the degradation of a stream flowing
through several properties. The required inputs and likely consequent outputs
(the transformation process) may not be known or be understood by all
parties. The process is not often repeated and thus requires intense
discussions, negotiations and personal trust (Mahoney
1992).
In transactions of this type there is
typically an inability to determine the rewards amongst participants because
the efforts of one party cannot be separated from those of another and,
because outcomes occur over a long period, output is difficult to monitor.
Mahoney calls this ‘low separability’. Even if the transformation process
is understood, because of common property characteristics, the knowledge that
an outcome will be achieved is not assured.
Because reward cannot be based on output,
behavior or effort must be monitored. Resource management arrangements with
these transaction characteristics are commonly best undertaken by cooperative
arrangements or relational contracts where obligations of parties are
specified and self enforced (Cary 2001).
Thus, there seems to be a place for manageably scaled community or clan
action that has yet to be fully developed.
There is a need to recognize the potential
contribution of community action for tackling land degradation problems.
However, it needs to be appreciated that community action is not a panacea
without other conditions necessary to bring about effective management
action. As appropriate cooperative arrangements and relational contracts
evolve, or are developed by groups of individuals, these need to be
documented and disseminated to reduce the transaction costs for others.
References
Cary, J.W. 2001,
‘Institutional innovation in natural resource management: A
conceptualization and some Australian examples’, in Wolf,
S. and Zilberman, D. (eds.), Knowledge
Generation and Technical Change: Institutional Innovation in Agriculture,
Kluwer, Boston.
Cary, J., Barr, N.,
Aslin, H., Webb, T. and Kelson, S. 2001, ‘Human and social aspects of
capacity to change to sustainable management practices’, Report for the
National Land and Water Resources Audit Theme 6 Projects 6.2.2 and 6.3.4,
Bureau of Rural Sciences, Canberra.
Cary, J.W., Webb, T.
and Barr, N.F. 2001, The adoption of
sustainable practices: Some new insights,
Bureau of Rural Sciences, Canberra.
Mahoney, J.T. 1992,
‘The choice of organizational form: Vertical financial ownership versus
other methods of vertical integration’, Strategic
Management Journal, vol 13, pp. 559-584.
Marra, M., Pannell, D.J.
and Abadi Ghadim, A. 2002, ‘The economics of risk, uncertainty and learning
in the adoption of new agricultural technologies: Where are we on the
learning curve?’ SEA Working Paper 01/10, Agricultural and Resource
Economics, University of Western Australia. http://www.general.uwa.edu.au/u/dpannell/dpap0110.htm
Mues, C., Chapman, L. and
Van Hilst, R. 1998, Landcare: Promoting
Improved Land Management Practices on Australian Farms: A Survey of Landcare
and Land Management Related Programs, ABARE, Canberra.
Pannell, D.J. 2001,
‘Explaining non-adoption of practices to prevent dryland salinity in
Western Australia: Implications for policy’, in Conacher, A. (ed.), Land
Degradation, Kluwer, Dordrecht.
Footnotes
ADDRESS: Bureau of Rural
Sciences, The University of Melbourne, Burnley College, Yarra Boulevard,
Richmond Vic 3121 Australia.
Email jcary@unimelb.edu.au
Landcare related work includes control of animal pests and weeds, fencing
for environmental protection, tree and shrub establishment, and setting
aside conservation areas.
In a similar analysis in an earlier study Mues et al (1998) found
membership of community landcare was significantly associated with the
adoption of two of five practices reported.
|